top of page

Why Save the Bankers?- By Piketty

eruditeevent

After more than a year of rising financial turmoil beginning in 2007, the crisis reached a climax on September 15, 2008, when Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy. This period witnessed a series of unprecedented government interventions aimed at restoring stability to the markets, including the Troubled Asset Relief Program (or TARP, a proposed $700 billion bailout) and billions of dollars in below-market loans and credit guarantees extended by the U.S. Treasury and Federal Reserve to a wide range of nonbank financial institutions that had never benefited from such assistance before. Many asked whether these moves marked the beginning of a new era of interventionist economic policy.


Will the financial crisis lead to the return of the state on the economic and social

scene? It’s too early to say. But it’s useful to dispel a few misunderstandings and

to clarify the terms of debate. The bank rescues and regulatory reforms

undertaken by the American government don’t in themselves constitute a

historic turning point. The speed and pragmatism with which the U.S. Treasury

and Federal Reserve adjusted their thinking and launched temporary

nationalizations of whole swaths of the financial system are certainly impressive.

And though it will take some time before we’ll know the final net cost to the

taxpayer, it’s possible that the scale of the interventions underway will surpass

levels reached in the past. Sums between $700 billion and $1.4 trillion are now

being discussed—between 5 and 10 percent of U.S. GDP—whereas the savings

and loan debacle of the 1980s cost around 2.5 percent.

Still, to a certain extent these kinds of interventions in the financial sector

represent a continuation of doctrines and policies already practiced in the past.

Since the 1930s, American elites have been convinced that the 1929 crisis

reached such great proportions and brought capitalism to the edge of the abyss

because the Federal Reserve and the public authorities let the banks collapse by

refusing to inject the liquidity needed to restore confidence and growth to the

productive sector. For some Americans on the free market right, faith in Fed

intervention goes hand in hand with a skepticism toward state intervention

outside the financial sphere: to save capitalism, we need a good Fed, flexible and

responsive—and certainly not a Rooseveltian welfare state, which would only

responsive—and certainly not a Rooseveltian welfare state, which would only

make Americans go soft. If we forget this historical context, we might be

surprised by the U.S. financial authorities’ swift intervention.

Will things stop there? That depends on the American presidential election: a

President Obama could seize this opportunity to strengthen the role of the state

in other areas beyond finance, for example in health insurance and reducing

inequality. But given the budgetary chasm left by the George W. Bush

administration (military spending, bank rescues), the room for maneuver on

health care might be limited—Americans’ willingness to pay more taxes is not

infinite. Moreover, the current debate in Congress on limiting finance sector pay

illustrates the ambiguities of today’s ideological context. One certainly senses

mounting public exasperation with the explosion of supersalaries for executives

and traders over the past thirty years. But the solution being envisaged, setting a

salary cap of $400,000 (the salary of the U.S. president) in financial institutions

bailed out by taxpayers, is a partial response that’s easily evaded—higher salary

payments just need to be transferred to other companies.

After the stock market crash of 1929, Franklin Roosevelt’s response to the

enrichment of the very economic and financial elites who had led the country

into the crisis was far more brutal. The federal tax rate on the highest incomes

was lifted from 25 to 63 percent in 1932, then to 79 percent in 1936, 91 percent

in 1941, then lowered to 77 percent in 1964, and finally 30–35 percent over the

course of the 1980s and 1990s by the Reagan and George H. W. Bush

administrations. For almost fifty years, from the 1930s until 1980, not only did

the top rate never fall below 70 percent, but it averaged more than 80 percent. In

the current ideological context, where the right to collect bonuses and golden

parachutes in the tens of millions without paying more than 50 percent in taxes

has been elevated to the status of a human right, many will judge those policies

primitive and confiscatory. But for more than half a century they were in effect

in the world’s largest democracy—clearly without preventing the American

economy from functioning. They had the particular virtue of drastically reducing

corporate executives’ incentive to dip their hands into the till, beyond a certain

threshold. With the globalization of finance, such policies could probably be

enacted only with a complete reworking of accounting disclosure rules, and

relentless efforts against tax havens. Unfortunately, it will probably take many

more crises to get there.

Recent Posts

See All

Comments


  • Instagram
Give Us Your Feedback

Thanks for submitting!

© 2023 by Contreverie. Proudly created by Aditya Das & Geetanjali 

bottom of page